Math Problem Statement
For each of the following utility functions, draw at least three indifference curves with small arrows pointing in the direction of preferred bundles, and explain whether the preferences represented by the utility functions are strictly convex. (c) π(π₯1, π₯2) = max{π₯1, 2π₯2}
Solution
Utility Function:
1. Interpretation of the Utility Function:
This utility function represents preferences where the consumer values and asymmetrically. Specifically, the utility is the maximum of and , meaning that:
- represents the consumption of good 1.
- represents the consumption of good 2, but doubled in value compared to .
Thus, for any bundle , the utility is determined by the larger of and . This implies that the consumer is indifferent between bundles where , and the utility increases as either or increases.
2. Indifference Curves:
The indifference curves for this utility function are determined by solving for , where is a constant utility level. Therefore, for each level :
- When , the utility is , so the indifference curve is a vertical line where .
- When , the utility is , so the indifference curve is a horizontal line where , or equivalently .
Thus, the indifference curves are composed of two segments:
- A vertical line for , when .
- A horizontal line for , when .
3. Direction of Preferred Bundles:
The consumer prefers bundles where either or is larger, with contributing equally to utility as . Therefore:
- Above the indifference curve, where either or is larger, utility is higher, and these bundles are preferred.
- The arrows indicating preferred directions would point upward and to the right.
4. Strict Convexity:
Strict convexity of preferences implies that the consumer strictly prefers a convex combination (i.e., a weighted average) of two bundles over the individual bundles themselves. However, in this case:
- The utility function leads to "kinked" indifference curves. Along the line , preferences switch from valuing to valuing .
- Because of these kinks, the preferences are not strictly convex. For example, the consumer is indifferent between bundles on the line where , but a convex combination of two such bundles will lie on the same indifference curve and not be strictly preferred.
Thus, the preferences are not strictly convex due to the presence of "corner" solutions where either or dominates utility.
Graph Explanation:
- Each indifference curve has two segments:
- A vertical part at (where ).
- A horizontal part at (where ).
- The curves are kinked at the line .
- Arrows should point toward regions where either or is increasing.
Would you like me to generate a visual representation of these indifference curves with arrows?
Follow-up Questions:
- What happens if the utility function treats and symmetrically, i.e., ?
- How do indifference curves look for ?
- Can preferences be non-convex but still satisfy monotonicity?
- What economic interpretation can you give for the non-convexity of these preferences?
- How does strict convexity relate to the concept of diminishing marginal rates of substitution?
Tip:
Strict convexity of preferences typically means that a consumer prefers averages of bundles over extremes, implying smooth and strictly convex indifference curves.
Ask a new question for Free
By Image
Drop file here or Click Here to upload
Math Problem Analysis
Mathematical Concepts
Microeconomics
Utility Functions
Convexity
Indifference Curves
Formulas
U(x1, x2) = max{x1, 2x2}
Theorems
Strict Convexity
Indifference Curve Theorem
Suitable Grade Level
Undergraduate Economics
Related Recommendation
Marginal Rate of Substitution and Convex Indifference Curves in Utility Functions
Utility Maximization and Slutsky Equation in Microeconomics
Utility Maximization and Budget Constraints: Cornfield's Preferences
Utility Maximization and Expenditure Minimization with Price and Income Changes
Slope of Indifference Curve for Utility Function u(x1, x2) = (x1^2)(x2^3)